342. Memorandum from Rashish to Ball, February 71

[Facsimile Page 1]

SUBJECT

  • Attached Memorandum on “Tax-sparing” provision in “double taxation treaties”

The attached memorandum from Ed Martin recommends that you approve the Department’s continuing support of tax-sparing provisions in our double taxation treaties with less developed countries. I recommend that you give your approval. This has been a Departmental policy and apparently has the approval of President Kennedy (see Attachment B). In any event the Department could ill-afford to revise its policy given the fact that three tax treaties, containing tax-sparing provisions, have been submitted to the Senate Foreign Relations Committee for approval.

There are some aspects of this problem, however, that are worth noting:

1. The past Administration’s commitment to tax-sparing came about, as I understand it, as a result of a visit by Secretary Anderson to an Inter-American conference and because of the pressure of a number of Latin American countries for negotiation of tax treaties containing such provisions.

2. It is not at all clear that the Congress approves of tax-sparing or, for that matter, that the Treasury Department will continue its adherence to the policy.

3. The Senate Foreign Relations Committee delayed in giving its approval to the first tax treaty containing a tax-sparing provision (that with Pakistan) and only did so after the Pakistani tax legislation had expired and the tax-sparing provision therefore was no longer operative. Stan Surrey, recently appointed Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Tax Policy, led the side against the Pakistan treaty. Moreover Wilbur Mills has made plain his opposition to tax-sparing, both on policy grounds as well as on jurisdictional grounds, i.e., he does not like the [Typeset Page 1503] idea of the Senate enacting what is in effect legislation reducing the incidents of domestic tax on domestic corporations.

[Facsimile Page 2]

4. In view of the above facts it is not at all certain that the Treasury Department’s position on tax-sparing will remain fixed. Indeed the Treasury may face opposition from within as well as from Congress in connection with the three treaties now before the Foreign Relations Committee. It is difficult to imagine how Surrey can defend the three treaties before this Committee having waged such a vigorous and successful campaign before the same Committee on the Pakistan treaty.

5. Therefore, although at the present time the Department’s position should be reaffirmed by you as a matter of general policy, it would be well to anticipate the difficulties that are likely to arise in obtaining Senate approval for the treaties and in particular the prospect of Treasury Department defection. I would therefore recommend that you talk to Secretary Dillon about his disposition on the matter and determine whether he proposes to hold the line in support of the three pending treaties.

[Facsimile Page 3]

Attachment

May we have an H clearance on the attached memorandum to Mr. Ball from Mr. Martin on the above subject. We would appreciate your returning this package to S/S by noon, Friday, February 3.

C.R. Hartley
[Facsimile Page 4]

Attachment

SUBJECT

  • Background Information on “tax-sparing”

Among the legislative inducements passed by less developed countries to attract new industry, there is typically included reduction or suspension of income tax. If the investors affected by these incentives also pay income tax in the United States, the tax credit provisions of the U.S. Internal Revenue Code will often reduce or cancel the incentive effect of the tax holiday, since the credit allowed against U.S. tax is generally reduced in the same amount that the foreign tax is decreased, leaving the taxpayer’s total tax liability unchanged. We seek to remove this frustrating effect of the U.S. tax credit by providing by treaty, in appropriate instances, a credit for the taxes spared, as if the spared taxes had in fact been paid.

There are at present before the Senate Foreign Relations Committee three treaties including such a provision—with India, Israel, and the [Typeset Page 1504] United Arab Republic. A brief discussion of the subject of tax treaties, with special attention to the tax sparing feature, taken from the testimony of Dan Throop Smith, Deputy to the Secretary of the Treasury, before the House Subcommittee on Foreign Trade Policy, is attached (Tab A). Passages dealing with tax sparing are marked in red. President Kennedy, in a letter to Business International, published in the October 28, 1960 issue (Tab B) declared, “. . . Specific resumes that should be considered include . . . a much more vigorous utilization of tax-sparing agreements abroad.”

There has been some opposition, spearheaded by Professor Stanley Surrey of the Harvard Law School, to the principle of granting credit for taxes spared. An extract of Professor Surrey’s testimony before the Foreign Relations Committee on August 9, 1957 [Facsimile Page 5] concerning the tax-sparing clause of the Pakistan treaty is attached (Tab C). Neither the Senate nor the Foreign Relations Committee has expressed a position on the principle of tax sparing. The only treaty ever submitted to the Senate providing credit for taxes spared, with the exception of the three now before the Committee, was that with Pakistan (1957). In that case, the Pakistan tax-sparing law expired before the Committee voted on the treaty. The Committee’s report on the treaty called for deletion of the tax-sparing provision on the grounds that it was most, without prejudice to future consideration of the principle in case the Pakistan law should be reenacted. The Senate gave its advice and consent to ratification on the basis of the Committee’s report.

The Treasury Department, in answer to an inquiry from Senator John J. Williams, agreed in October 1960 not to undertake further negotiations of treaties containing tax-sparing provisions until the Senate’s position on the principle was known, except in cases where negotiations were already at an advanced stage. The State Department’s reply to a similar letter (Tab D) avoided making any commitment of this nature.

It has been proposed, as for instance, in H.R. 5 of the 86th Congress (the Boggs Bill) that credit for taxes spared be granted unilaterally by U.S. legislation. The Department of State and Treasury feel that the provision should remain in the field of treaties (or possibly of executive agreements, if statutory authorization were given). If such a credit were authorized unilaterally by tax legislation, the U.S. would relinquish a large degree of the relativity it now exercises over the foreign tax concessions eligible for credit. Moreover, the prospect of tax sparing is the principal inducement we can offer to lose developed countries to enter into tax treaties with us. If this benefit were granted unilaterally, its incentive effect would be lost.

[Typeset Page 1505]

Tab A

[Facsimile Page 6]

Extract from Statement of Hon. Dan Throop Smith, Deputy to the Secretary of the Treasury (in charge of Tax Policy), before the Subcommittee on Foreign Trade Policy of the Committee on Ways and Means, House of Representatives, in its hearings on Private Foreign Investment, December 1, 1958.

The basic provisions of the tax law applicable to income from foreign sources are supplemented by a network of 21 income-tax treaties which help eliminate tax barriers to the international movement of trade and investment. Their principal purpose is to set forth agreed rules of source, either explicitly or implicitly, through reciprocal tax-rate reductions and exemptions, which reduce the cases in which two countries impose tax on the same income without either one giving recognition to the tax imposed by the other.

Let me illustrate the problem.

While we allow a credit for the tax imposed by country X on income derived in that country, our concepts of source may differ from those accepted in the foreign country. As a result, there may be a flow of income to an American firm which is considered under United States law to be income from sources within the United States, but which under the laws of the foreign country may be considered income from sources within its borders. Both countries would impose a tax on that income, but we would not allow a credit for the foreign tax, since the income does not have its origin in that country so far as the United States law is concerned.

With tax rates as they are, the combined tax burden in such a case might well exceed the total income involved. This problem arises, in greater or lesser degree, in connection with various types of international transactions, including trading activities, the rendition of personal services, licensing arrangements, and the like.

Mr. Chairman, if I may, I would like to emphasize the importance of this point I have just mentioned. It is often, I think, overlooked in discussions on the subject and thought of as simply something of a technical nature to be worked out. But it is a thing that does call for bilateral agreements for each country to accede to some degree in its basic concepts. We regard it as a key element in our treaty program, and that is one reason why we are anxious to extend the treaties.

Of late we have undertaken another step in connection with the tax-treaty program which holds considerable promise of facilitating the international movement of investment. I refer to the credit for tax incentives or tax sparing which some less-developed countries have chosen to use as part of their programs to attract capital and know-how from abroad and to encourage reinvestment of profits.

[Typeset Page 1506]

The tax-credit mechanism designed to achieve equality of tax burdens operates so as to offset, to some extent, tax incentives granted by a foreign country. For, as the tax imposed in a foreign country is reduced, whatever the reason may be, the amount of the tax credit allowed against United States tax is also reduced. When the tax credit declines, the amount of United States tax payable tends [Facsimile Page 7] to increase, and thus to negate the tax reduction offered by the foreign country.

This has been a source of irritation among some foreign countries. Though it may not be desirable from the point of view of an ideal tax system, uniformly administered, to give a credit for an amount of tax which has not been collected by a foreign government, it is our view that, in the interest of foreign economic policy, we should recognize, rather than nullify, the revenue sacrifices made by a foreign government under certain conditions. This question is developed more fully at a later point. . . . (pp. 46–47)

One objective of the tax proposals under review is to make it possible for American firms investing abroad to benefit from the tax inducements offered by foreign governments to attract new capital. As previously noted, such inducements can now be taken advantage of by a foreign subsidiary engaged in business abroad and seeking to plow back its earnings.

However, if a business is conducted abroad through a branch, or if the opportunity and desire to reinvest are lacking, then the tax incentive offered by a foreign country is offset by operation of our tax system. This problem has already been mentioned, but the declaration of policy which the administration has made in connection with the tax-treaty program may be repeated at this point.

It has announced that we are prepared to consider the inclusion in tax treaties with less developed countries of a provision by which recognition would be given to tax-incentive schemes under so-called pioneer industries legislation or laws for the development of new and necessary industries.

Briefly, what we are proposing is this:

If a country believes that by giving up tax revenues in certain cases, it will be serving the cause of economic development, we will forego the opportunity to increase our tax revenues by nullifying their concessions. However, we would be prepared to forego this only under certain conditions.

First, there should be a firm commitment to eliminate unnecessary and inequitable tax barriers to the flow of private investment in accordance with sound rules of taxation such as are generally embodied in our income-tax treaties. This includes agreement not to discriminate against American business enterprises.

[Typeset Page 1507]

Second, its tax incentive laws should be of general application, thus assuring maximum benefit to the economy from such legislation.

Third, the conditions and terms under which the tax incentives are available should be those provided in an existing law with full disclosure of the conditions under which they are granted, and with procedures for granting or withholding tax incentives which involve a minimum of administrative discretion.

Fourth, the tax incentive should be for a limited duration of time, and preferably limited in amount.

Finally, the tax from which exemption is granted must be a genuine part of the country’s tax structure and not a spurious levy created for the occasion.

[Facsimile Page 8]

Whatever one may think about a credit for taxes spared as an element in an ideal tax system, and there are some who have misgivings, it is our view that this is a sensible way to approach an issue that is of considerable importance to foreign countries and that has the seeds of substantial growth in promoting private investment abroad at a minimum cost.

It may be said of the tax treaty programs that a credit for taxes spared permits foreign governments to determine the tax burden imposed on American firms and to vary that tax burden among American firms in different ways. In a broad sense, this is quite correct. However, it is a charge that is equally true of any method of taxing foreign income which in any way removes income from the scope of the United States tax. It is true in large measure today of income derived abroad through foreign subsidiaries. (pp. 51–52)

  1. Tax-sparing provisions in LDC double taxation treaties. Attachment provides additional background information. Official Use Only. 8 pp. Department of State, Central Files, 611.00431/2–761.