Mr. Denby to Mr. Olney.

No. 2670.]

Sir: In my dispatch No. 2614, of October 18 last, I inclosed a copy of a communication sent by me, as dean of the corps diplomatique, to the Shanghai General Chamber of Commerce, wherein it was stated that the foreign representatives acquiesced in the suggestion for the appointment of a committee of merchants to inquire into and report on the taxation of foreign trade in China.

This suggestion was adopted by the chamber of commerce. A committee was formed, including representatives of every branch of commerce, and was divided into subcommittees. These subcommittees are now engaged in compiling materials for sectional reports. To these reports will be added such further information as may be obtained from the chambers of commerce at the treaty ports.

The chamber has adopted the plan of forwarding to the foreign representatives copies of each sectional report as soon as it is prepared. I have received the report of the sectional committee on cotton mills, and I inclose a copy thereof herewith. This report sets forth the reasons and arguments on which foreign cotton mill owners in Shanghai base their claim to moderate taxation of their manufactures. The question of raising the tariff rate is left out of consideration. This question can not be entirely eliminated from a discussion on taxation. The sole purpose of China is to raise more revenue, of which it stands in great need. Whether such revenue shall be raised by increasing the tariff only, or by local taxation, or by both means, must be discussed and decided.

The report under consideration assumes that, under the fourth clause of the second section of Article VI of the Shimoneseki treaty, articles manufactured in China were to stand on the same footing as imported articles. It concedes that this provision has been surrendered by Japan (see 2616 of October 20, 1896), but it claims that the cotton mills, which were organized before the annulment of this clause, and on the assumption that they would be exempt from taxation, are entitled to exemption. How this contention might affect claims for damages need not now be discussed, but that it would legally bar the levy of any tax can not be admitted, more especially as China always disputed the Japanese construction of the clause as to taxation.

This portion of the report is, therefore, not entitled to any consideration.

The first principle enunciated is that the cotton industry should be fostered by freedom from taxation, but if that be impossible, “the duty or excise should never exceed the duty levied upon imported yarn [Page 89] less the transit duty paid upon the raw cotton which enters into its manufacture.”

For the argument on this subject I refer to the report itself.

The second suggestion is that raw cotton purchased in the interior for treatment in the mills shall pay transit duty as if destined for export, and no other duty.

The third suggestion is that all imported cotton should be free from duty.

The fourth suggestion is that foreign-owned mills shall enjoy the same privileges as native mills.

The committee proceeds to state that any higher taxation than that suggested will result in the loss of China’s advantageous position as a manufacturing country. The committee enlarges on the advantages of cheap labor and raw material, the value of the trade to China, the absence of taxation on cotton in India and America, the injustice of a 10 per cent tax, and other matters going to support the argument in favor of a low taxation.

It is apparent from this report that the committee looks chiefly to securing benefits for the foreign mill owner operating in China. Incidentally the benefits to accrue to China are considered. Nowhere, however, is any question raised as to the interests of the manufacturers in the United States and in Europe. As I have repeatedly stated in former dispatches, I am unable to see how the interests of my own country are to be forwarded by fostering cotton manufacturing in China. I believe, also, that all questions affecting taxation of foreign goods should be treated together.

I await your instructions on the questions involved.

I have, etc.,

Charles Denby.
[Inclosure in No. 2670.]

Report of the sectional committee on cotton mills, in which are set forth the reasons and arguments on which foreign cotton-mill owners in Shanghai base their claim to moderate and equitable taxation of their manufactures.

In the communication addressed to the doyen of the corps diplomatique, at Pekin, by the chamber of commerce on 17th September were contained certain suggestions as to the taxation of locally spun yarns, together with an outline of the procedure which, in the chamber’s opinion, would best serve to foster a new industry and, at the same time, benefit the Imperial revenue. Those suggestions were put forward, however, upon the supposition that a revision of the treaty tariff was under contemplation, and the chamber of commerce was, at that date, unacquainted with the since-published text of the treaty of commerce and navigation between China and Japan. But since, by Article XXVI of that treaty, the question of tariff revision appears to be removed from the necessity of immediate consideration, the suggestions submitted by the chamber, so far as they are based on that expectation, are no longer pertinent. This committee begs, therefore, to reopen the subject and, putting aside all question of increased import duties, to deal with the position of Shanghai foreign-owned cotton mills.

And first this committee would point out that, though the importation of industrial machinery was not excluded under treaty rights, all doubt on the subject was removed on the concession by China of manufacturing rights under the Shimonoseki treaty, and the commencement of foreign-owned mills was the result. The terms of that concession have, it is true, been materially affected since then by the protocol of 19th October (Article III), but it was owing to the nature of the terms set forth in the Shimonoseki treaty that capital was forthcoming to establish these enterprises, and this committee ventures to submit that, howsoever those terms may have been modified by subsequent negotiations between China and Japan, all mills built before the publication of the protocol are morally entitled to such advantages as they would have enjoyed under the terms of the treaty itself. The existing mills [Page 90] were established and much capital invested therein on the assumption that they would be exempt from taxation; and to impose a high rate of duty now would, in this committee’s opinion, be an act not only highly prejudicial, but one from which the Government would derive no lasting benefit.

After mature deliberation on the subject, the committee urges as conditions essential to the prosperity of the cotton industry in China:

1. That the industry should be fostered by freedom from taxation, but if this be impossible and the Chinese Government determined to tax it, the duty, or excise, should never exceed the duty levied upon imported yarn less the transit duty paid upon the raw cotton which enters into its manufacture.

Cotton in imported yarn does not yield revenue to the Chinese Government as cotton, and were locally spun yarn to be taxed at the same rate as imported yarn the cotton in it would be twice taxed, first as cotton and secondly in yarn. Upon the scale of duty the excise upon locally spun yarn would therefore be:

Hk. tls.
Import duty on 3 piculs Yarn 2.10
Less transit duty on 3 piculs 40 catties cotton used to produce it. .60
Leaving 1.50

or 5 mace per picul as the duty or excise upon locally spun yarn.

Upon payment of this excise a certificate should be issued entitling the yarn to all the privileges and exemptions enjoyed by imported yarn.

That upon payment of a further half duty, i.e., 3 mace 5 candareens per picul, or, say, 1.05 taels per bale, transit certificate should be issued which shall afford the yarn, whether sent inland or shipped to other treaty ports for transmission to the interior, freedom from likin, inland transit, internal taxes, duties, charges, and exactions of all kinds.

2. That raw cotton purchased in the interior and brought to Shanghai, or any other treaty port, for treatment in the mills, shall pay transit duty as upon cotton destined for export, this payment freeing it absolutely from all likin and other exactions en route, and it is suggested that the amount collected in this way might be devoted to the use of the provincial authorities concerned in its levy.

3. That foreign-owned mills shall enjoy the same privileges as native mills, i.e., that there shall be no differential taxation of any sort. (N. B.—Article III of the Tokyo protocol provides for condition.)

This committee is firmly convinced, by careful study of facts and figures, that any attempt on the part of the Chinese Government to provide a large immediate revenue by higher taxation of yarn than that suggested above can have but one result, viz, the loss of China’s advantageous position as a manufacturing country. Cheap labor and raw material can enable her to compete with foreign countries in the cotton manufacturing industry only so long as she does not hamper that industry by impolitic and excessive taxation. This committee would therefore urge the vital necessity which exists for the Peking Government to restrain the provincial authorities from imposing levies on the raw material which would check production.

There can be little doubt that the manufacture of yarn in China, if wisely safeguarded and developed, must rapidly produce a volume of trade that will greatly contribute to the prosperity of the country, compared to which the amount that might be levied by impolitic taxation is a matter of insignificance; a trade which would not only enrich the Imperial treasury, but which would give employment to large and increasing numbers of the laboring classes. An unwise fiscal policy at this juncture on the part of China will simply result in benefiting other manufacturing countries at her expense, and a new industry of great promise will be destroyed at its very outset.

In foreign countries, such as India and America, which compete with China as producers of the raw material, no taxes are imposed on cotton. Similarly, in India and Japan (China’s competitors in the yarn manufacture) no taxes are levied on the product of the mills. The only charges, therefore, which Indian or Japanese yarns incur are freight, insurance, and import duty.

Freight is a variable charge. From India it has been as low as 7 mace per bale, and is at present the equivalent of 1.05 haikwan taels per bale. Insurance is about 25 candareens per bale. Import duty is 2.10 haikwan taels per bale.

The total charge on Indian yarn varies, therefore, between 3.05 and 3.40 haikwan taels per bale, and on Japanese yarn, spun from Indian and American cotton, it may be set down as being very little higher.

In a recent proclamation, issued by the governor of Chekiang, new cotton likin regulations are published. Amongst them is set forth that the tax (likin) on seed cotton sent to Shanghai from that province will be 40 cents a bale, which amounts to a tax of 2.65 haikwan taels on the quantity of cleaned cotton required to make a bale of yarn and the average charges on Indian yarn, exclusive of duty, being, say, [Page 91] 1.12 haikwan taels per bale, it is evident that under these regulations the Shanghai spinner would be placed at considerable disadvantage. If, in addition to this, the Tsung-li Yamên’s proposed 10 per cent tax be imposed, the total taxation on locally-made yarn would amount to 8.85 haikwan taels per bale, as against 2.10 haikwan taels, the duty on imported yarn. In other words, foreign industry would be protected against native to the extent of 6.75 haikwan taels per bale. Such a policy could have but one result—native spinning being rendered unprofitable, the industry would soon cease to exist.

It is the desire of this committee, and one for which they venture to ask the earnest cooperation and support of the diplomatic body in Pekin, that the tax on raw cotton in transit from the interior be met by one payment of transit pass duty, such payment freeing the cotton from likin and all other exactions, and that the central Government be strongly urged to make and enforce a regulation to this effect. Such transit duty, together with the proposed excise of 1.50 haikwan taels, as shown in paragraph 1, would amount to a total payment of 2.10 haikwan taels per bale, against 2.10 haikwan taels levied on foreign yarn, a tax which the mill-owners have some hope that the industry could pay without endangering the financial success of their enterprise.

At present Shanghai native-spun yarns pay no duty, so that by the imposition of a reasonable tax on all mills, native and foreign, a large and immediate increase will accrue to the Imperial revenue without injury to manufacturing and commercial interests.

In conclusion, the committee feels that it can not do better than quote the following just and reasonable words from the Tsung-li Yamên’s memorial to the Throne (August, 1895):

“It is very necessary to settle uniform tariff regulations without making distinctions by virtue of which some pay heavier and others lighter duties, so that it may be easy for all to conform therewith.”

It is the committee’s earnest hope that only such moderate and equitable taxation may be imposed as shall tend to the mutual benefit of the Imperial treasury and of the commercial enterprises whose interests the committee represents.

  • E. A. Alford,
  • E. A. Probts,
  • F. Anderson,
    Members Sectional Committee on Cotton Mill Taxation.