On February 25 the Economic Policy Board directed its constituent agencies to
form a task force to reexamine U.S. commodity policy for non-fuel minerals
and report its findings to the Board on April 30.
Attached is the report summarizing the task force’s findings. The body of the
report, which is presently several hundred pages long, will be forwarded as
soon as it has been edited.
Attachment
Summary of Report to Economic Policy Board on Commodity
Policy for Non-Fuel Minerals
I. Background
This reexamination of commodities policy was undertaken in anticipation
of increasing pressure in international forums for commodities
agreements and out of concern that the commodity market instabilities of
the 1972–74 period might mark the dawn of a new era for which past
commodity policy was no longer suited. Consequently, this study aims to
assess the likelihood that we are in a new era, analyze the merits of
the major new commodity proposals, and, to the extent time permitted,
assess the alternatives and point out areas where further consideration
might be fruitful.
To permit more intensive analysis, the Board accepted the task force’s
recommendations that the study focus on the six non-fuel
[Page 991]
minerals which the less developed
countries identified in UNCTAD as
suitable for commodity agreements. These six account for more than half
the value of U.S. non-fuel mineral imports.
II. Conclusions
Our tentative conclusions for the six minerals studies are as
follows:
1. This study tends to confirm the desirability of continuing our long
standing existing commodities policy: a preference for non-interference
by governments but a willingness to entertain proposals on a case by
case and commodity by commodity basis.
- a.
-
No New Era—The extreme volatility of the
commodity markets during the 1972–74 period is more likely to prove
the exception than the rule. While business cycles will be more
synchronized in the future than during the average of the 1960s, the
extraordinary amplitude and synchronization of the 1972–74 period
are not likely to be recurrent. The market instability during this
period was exacerbated by an unusual amount of speculative
buying.
- b.
-
Commodity Agreements In General Are Not the
Answer: Economic or Political—The commodity proposals which
have been tabled internationally rely on two major mechanisms: a
price setting mechanism and a buffer stockpile to support it. We
looked at the likelihood that such agreements would provide a
solution to the problems of commodity markets. Our conclusion is
that the prospects, in general, are not good.
Economic Value
First the benefits are not certain. While stabilization seems a desirable
goal to some, short term stabilization can lead to longer term
instability. Past agreements for tropical products have only been
marginally successful and never last long. The evidence of benefits is
at best inconclusive.
On the other hand, for most of the six commodities studied, the evidence
of high economic costs is fairly clear:
- i.
-
The LDCs in UNCTAD have proposed
commodity agreements for these commodites, yet less than 10
percent of U.S. imports of these commodities come from
LDCs. To sustain the
price for this 10 percent through agreement would probably
require imposing import/export controls, domestic production
controls, or quotas with their attendant costs in
administration and market disruption. Moreover, it would be
technically difficult to implement an agreement for one of
these commodities—iron ore.
If a buffer stockpile were used, the capital cost would be
quite high—our econometric model suggested $1.2–4.8 billion
for copper,
[Page 992]
lead
and zinc—and it is not really technically feasible for iron
ore. Moreover, some, including many in industry, believe
buffer stockpiling would interfere with the investment
process.
- ii.
-
Bauxite and Tin—Bauxite (aluminum
ore) does not appear to be a serious candidate for a
commodity agreement or buffer stockpile. It is traded
primarily between different parts of integrated companies,
ore grades differ, and no real market reference price
exists. Even the producer countries don’t seem to think a
price agreement is feasible: they have relied on export
taxes to increase their revenues.
For twenty years a tin buffer stock agreement has existed in
which all major consumers and producers except the U.S. have
participated. Its impact on the market is difficult to
assess but it will shortly be renegotiated and the U.S. may
be pressed to join. This study reached no significant
specific conclusions, positive or negative, with respect to
tin.
- iii.
-
Qualification—Our conclusions, based on a
two month study, are not so negative that we would preclude
further study of these commodities on a case by case basis. The
likelihood of anything beneficial emerging in general seems
slight, but further consideration of both the tin agreement and
buffer stockpiles for copper seem warranted. Our econometric
buffer stockpile studies, possibly the first of their kind,
suggest that in theory, at least, a buffer stockpile could be
useful. The capital cost is very high—in the billions—but
sharing with other consumers and producers might reduce U.S.
costs below $1 billion.
Political
For the four domestically produced commodities—copper, lead, zinc, and
iron ore—commodity agreements will prove a very unsatisfactory response
to the LDCs’ political pressure for
better terms of trade (resource transfer). While a few LDCs might benefit significantly, as
previously indicated, only $1 out of every additional $10 spent by the
U.S. consumer through higher prices for these commodities will go to the
LDCs. The other $9 will go to
producers in the U.S. and the resource rich developed countries, notably
Australia and Canada.
If resource transfer is the objective, direct aid is more satisfactory
for these four minerals. If commodity agreements are used, the LDCs can be expected to renew their demands
in a few years. They will correctly maintain they benefited very little
from agreements despite the fact that the U.S. consumer paid a high
price. By that time, an artificial pricing structure would have been
created that would be politically difficult to disassemble.
III. Alternatives
Alternatives to commodity agreements were considered. One is to
strengthen the market mechanism through better information exchange,
[Page 993]
intergovernmental
consultation, futures markets, and through pursuit of supply access
agreements in the MTN negotiations.
These steps would reduce the information scarcity and anxiety over
supplies which contributed to excessive speculation during the 1972–74
period.
If direct aid to the LDCs is considered
necessary for political reasons, then compensatory financing like the
Lome (Stabex) agreement3 which the Europeans recently signed could be
considered. The economic effects seem to be minimal—but it has political
appeal, perhaps because, like the lottery, the actual return to
individual countries may substantially exceed the average expected
return.
Another alternative is an economic emergency stockpile. It would make
supplies available in times of extreme shortage. Sales would be
authorized under very stringent conditions, such as those required for
imposing export controls. It would primarily aim to help consumers, but
would have some immediate appeal for producing countries because
stockpile purchases will strengthen prices. It has attracted some
legislative attention and will be studied further by the forthcoming
Commission on Supplies and Shortages.
IV. Further Study
Time constraints prevented adequate consideration of other commodity
related issues. One which clearly deserves further study is how a better
international climate for priviate investment in natural resources can
be created. In 1973, 80 percent of exploration investment for non-fuel
minerals was made in four developed countries. This means economically
marginal deposits are being exploited because private investors consider
the climate in developing countries too hostile for investment. A change
in this climate would benefit both developed and developing countries. A
real opportunity for mutual benefit may lie here.