CFM Files: Lot M–88: Box 93: File—Germany Reparations II

The Special Adviser to the Secretary of State on Reparations (Pauley) to the Secretary of State 62

secret

My Dear Mr. Secretary: On April 30, 1947, you asked me as Special Advisor on Reparations, to submit to you a proposed German reparations plan in anticipation of the Council of Foreign Ministers meeting in London.

The objective of such a plan would be to facilitate a general settlement of Central European problems, contemplating, among other [Page 714] things, unification of Germany. I have worked, through my staff, in close association with the regular divisions of the Department which have been considering these problems. The consensus in the Department has been that bare economic unification would be a delusion unless coupled with a great many other considerations. I share that view.

I have explored the reparations question in all its aspects. I am submitting a paper comprising a detailed discussion of the reparations problem, and its economic and political implications. There is included as an appendix a summary of pertinent statistical and economic data.

I am now convinced that a practical reparations offer alone could not constitute a sufficient inducement to Soviet Russia to obtain agreement to all the political and economic conditions which we believe necessary for a European settlement. Nevertheless, I believe a definitive reparations offer should be made at London, in association with other inducements, to indicate our desire to abide by our past commitments and to require the German economy to assist, to its practical maximum, in the recovery of Europe including the recovery of Russia. I believe such an offer is strategically essential to counter Russia’s current offensive which is designed, I believe, to indicate to the world that the United States is seeking selfish ends, even at the cost of war. I have included in the attached documents a political discussion developing this viewpoint and its implications.

After detailed consideration of many alternative reparations formulas, I have returned to the proposal you made at Moscow in March, 1947.63 Bearing in mind the conditions you attached to that proposal, I have suggested a means of meeting those conditions.

In brief, my proposal, which is expanded at length in the attached Paper, provides for the grant to all reparations claimants of a reparations credit, redeemable in finished and processed goods, equivalent to the value of the capital installations the claimants would have received from the Western Zones under the 1946 level of industry, but retained in Germany under a new level of industry to be finally decided upon at London. This level, I assume, is to be roughly equivalent to the 1947 bizonal level. The reparations credit is to be available only upon the condition that reparations claimants furnish for the German economy food, fuel, raw materials or acceptable equivalents required to enable the German economy to produce the finished goods in question. If necessary, the 15 per cent of Western Zone capital removals provided under the terms of the Potsdam Agreement for the USSR and Poland in exchange for reciprocal deliveries of specified commodities could be [Page 715] equated to a separate reparations credit to be divided between the IARA countries and the USSR-Poland. It is suggested that the reparations credit could be based upon the in-place value of the capital equipment previously scheduled for removal but now to be retained in Germany. I believe that a level of industry roughly equivalent to the 1947 bizonal level could easily support such a program. This reparations program, itself, would assist in activating idle German capacity that would not otherwise be utilized. It would not involve, of itself, expenditures by the United States. It is, therefore, consistent with our major objectives.

It is recommended that despite interdepartmental commitments, there be a new level of industry determination based upon whatever agreements are made, whether among all four occupying powers, or only with Britain and France.

Inasmuch as Soviet spokesmen have repeatedly gone on record as demanding $10 billion in reparations, you might consider it desirable to accept a formula by which past Soviet-Polish removals from Germany plus reparations collectible in the future could be computed for the record, at $10 billion. This, of course, would be predicated upon prior agreement on the actual amount of future reparations for Russia and Poland.

It is recommended that removals as reparations of all capital equipment in excess of the new level of industry be promptly resumed and completed.

It is implicit that the above plan and the negotiating variants suggested in the attached paper are based upon the satisfaction of the politico-economic conditions to be proposed as terms of a general European settlement.

In my judgment, the forthcoming CFM meeting will be one of transcendental significance. It will constitute one of the Great Divides of American policy in this era. I am grateful for the opportunity given me to advise you in this situation.

Respectfully,

Edwin W. Pauley
[Annex]

Paper on German Reparations, Prepared by the Special Adviser to the Secretary of State on Reparations (Pauley)

secret

I—Summary of Separations Paper

Situation

At Moscow Secretary Marshall agreed to consider equating once-for-all removals due each recipient nation under the 1946 level of industry to current production, with the reservation that any such [Page 716] plan must not increase the financial burden on the American Government and should not interfere with the prospects of Germany’s attaining an economic balance.

In the summer of 1946, at Paris, Russia made a demand for $10 billion in reparations, mostly out of current production, a demand which she had not voiced since Potsdam; the USSR indicated a desire to raise the level of industry to make possible reparations out of current production. The USSR is believed to have taken this position because of disappointment with the economic benefits, to her, of capital removals. Russia vigorously restated this position at Moscow in March, 1947, and rejected the American argument that the Potsdam Reparations formula had extinguished all previous Russian reparations demands.

It can be assumed, for the sake of negotiations, that Russia’s intransigent position on unification and reparations is due to a desire to obtain the maximum amount of industrial and consumer goods from Germany, to meet internal political prestige needs and to help rebuild the Soviet industrial machine. The United States, therefore, might advantageously propose a settlement which might make available to the USSR the maximum amount of goods from Germany consistent with the other imperatives of American policy, namely, economic self-sufficiency for Germany at the earliest possible date, and the economic recovery and political stability of Europe, especially of Western Europe.

It is believed that no feasible reparations offer can be devised of sufficient scope to induce Russia to agree to both the economic and political conditions required by the United States for a general settlement of Central European problems. Nevertheless, it is manifest that we should attempt to gain acceptance of a reparations settlement which will, as nearly as possible, accomplish our goals of European recovery and the industrial disarmament of Germany. It is psychologically important that the United States emphasize its desire to require Germany to contribute, through reparations, to the recovery of Europe, while also pointing out that the recovery of Germany would be in itself a contribution to European recovery.

Capacity of Germany to Provide Reparations

The German economic situation is such as to preclude any program of “pure” reparations out of current production regardless of any further increases in the level of industry. Actual production is restricted by shortages of (a) coal, (b) food, (c) transport, (d) raw materials, (e) housing, and by dislocations in manpower and management. Most of the shortages are in categories of which there are world shortages. Almost all import requirements of the German economy require dollars; German production cannot increase to major [Page 717] proportions without such imports because of the lack of indigenous resources. Economic unification of Germany would only reduce to an unestablished extent, but would not eliminate, the deficit in the German economy under present circumstances. Any program of “pure” reparations out of current production would thus be at the expense of the nation or nations supporting the German deficit. Germany’s import requirements, which will increase in proportion to increased industrial production, include: food, petroleum products, rubber, iron ore, copper, almost all other non-ferrous metals, cotton, wool, hides, fertilizer, and basic chemicals.

There is no foreseeable possibility of a full restoration of Germany’s prewar export markets, because of (a) increased indigenous production in former market countries, (b) political antipathies and fears resulting from war, (c) increased nationalism throughout Europe, (d) shortage of dollars in Germany’s former markets, (e) inability of former market countries to supply Germany with Germany’s import needs such as food and raw materials, (f) current political and economic orientation of Balkan and Eastern European nations to the USSR; these countries were formerly dependent to a major extent on Germany for their external trade.

At the same time it must be a major objective to give certainty to the German economy so that, at the earliest possible date, the German people, having made their contribution to the recovery of the victim nations, can aim at the goal of national improvement in the standard of living, and cooperation with other European nations in the solution of continental economic problems.

Nature of Reparations Program

The United States is committed to the principles of Potsdam including a reparations program. The United States has been one of the chief protagonists of once-for-all removals both to reduce the German war potential and to help raise the standard of living of the nations against whom Germany waged war and occupied. It is to America’s interest to support a reparations program, including a continuation of capital removals, both to give support to democratic forces in Western Europe and to discharge implied commitments to potential reparations recipients for whom the United States was, by implication, the spokesman and agent at Potsdam.

There is no economic prospect for the utilization of all standing plant capacity now in Germany in the foreseeable future. Even without the existing bottlenecks to increased production, much of the standing equipment is autarchic, uneconomic in present relation to transport and sources of raw materials, and geared to a wartime instead of a peacetime economy. Most of this excess capacity was built up during the period of preparation for aggression. Its removal would [Page 718] not interfere with Germany’s economic recovery, while its transfer to other countries would aid in their rehabilitation and the establishment of a more balanced economy in Europe. In the long run, these removals would be a boon to German economic regrowth on a sound and integrated basis.

A limited program of reparations out of current production, along the lines of Secretary Marshall’s Moscow proposal, could be so arranged as to be economically feasible and consistent with German economic recovery. The reparations plan proposed below would require claimant nations to provide food, fuel or raw materials to the German economy as part payment for manufactured goods to be received as reparations. Although most of the raw material and fuel resources of Western Europe have already been committed under the terms of the European Recovery Program, some of these nations have food surpluses of a certain category (such as eggs, vegetables, and fats) and others might be able to obtain raw material or other commodities required by the German economy which the countries in question would be willing to supply to Germany in return for a greater quantity of manufactured goods than they would otherwise be able to obtain by outright purchases from Germany or imports from other areas.

Reparations Negotiations and Plan

It is recommended that the United States propose the following plans and seek agreement or agree to the following conditions:

A.

A program of limited reparations out of current production, the total amount of which is to be equated to the removal value of capital equipment scheduled to be awarded as reparations under the 1946 Level of Industry Plan, but to be retained in Germany under the new level: Provided that each claimant country agrees to supply in acceptable commodities (food, fuel, or raw materials) a portion of the value of finished goods delivered, the remainder of the value of which is to be considered the reparations payment.

As a variant to this proposal, the Secretary might agree to equate the value of current reparations credit to the in-place value of the capital equipment in question. This would increase the value by approximately 70 per cent.

This program would be projected over a five-year period; all “payments” of commodities would be delivered within that period; the reparations deliveries would be consummated within the shortest possible time, but not necessarily within the five-year period.

B.
The percentage of the total “reparations credit” to be allowed USSR–Poland would be as in the Potsdam Agreement. If it is desired to make an additional concession on this proposal, it is suggested that the 15 per cent of capital removals provided in exchange for commodity deliveries be divided equally between USSR–Poland and the IARA nations. Percentages for the IARA nations would be as in the Paris Agreement. The Potsdam provision for “reciprocal deliveries” would be eliminated. The assent of the IARA nations would be required to make this arrangement.
C.
As an alternative, it might be proposed that there be a resumption of the capital removals program on the above percentage basis, without current reparations.
D.
Capital removals above the 1947 level of industry (or the level suggested in “E” below) would be resumed to all claimants.
E.
The level of industry would be reviewed, at a technical level, in the light of economic unification, the type of reparations program adopted and other current factors, by representatives of the appropriate occupying powers.
F.
Inasmuch as Soviet spokesmen have repeatedly gone on record as demanding $10 billion in reparations from Germany, the internal political needs of the government of Soviet Russia might be satisfied by a formula under which past Soviet-Polish removals from Germany, as reparations collectible in the future, could be computed, for the record, at $10 billion, provided that agreement were first reached as to the actual amount of future reparations.
G.
Whatever reparations plan is agreed upon should constitute a final settlement of all reparations claims by all nations.
H.
The administration of Plan A would be left to the Allied Control Council and its economic agencies, including the determination of plants to be utilized for reparations work, the types of finished goods to be available for reparations, and the commodities to be considered acceptable in return for finished goods.
I.
It is implicit that all of the above offers by the United States would be contingent upon Soviet agreement to the politico-economic conditions deemed essential for a German settlement including political and economic unification.
J.
If the USSR declines to accept any of our reparations proposals and refuses a major settlement of German problems, it is recommended that the United States resume immediate capital reparations deliveries to the IARA nations but continue indefinitely the suspension of deliveries to the USSR and Poland.

[The remainder of this paper, covering fifty-five pages in the typewritten source text, is not printed. It was arranged under the following sub-headings: Political Observations, Level of Industry and Economic Unification, Reparations Plan and Negotiations, Negotiations with the USSR, First Chargé Principle, Reparations Background, Present Status of the Reparations Program, Capital Removals vs Current Production, Analysis of European Economic Problems, Role of Coal, and Statistical Appendix.]

  1. This communication was forwarded to the Secretary of State under cover of a memorandum, dated November 13, 1947, which read as follows:

    “In accordance with the Secretary’s instructions, I have considered my work on reparations an integral part of the functions of the State Department and have worked and consulted closely with those in the Department responsible for policy on the political and economic affairs of Europe. In this, as in other reparations matters, I worked, through my staff, in close association with the Assistant Secretary for Occupied Areas. On the suggestion of Assistant Secretary Hilldring, and with the agreement of his successor, Secretary Saltzman, my deputy, Commander Julius C. Edelstein, has served simultaneously as a member of the staff of the Assistant Secretary. The reparations study being submitted has been worked out following such consultations.

    “It was expected at first that it would be unnecessary to submit a separate report, but it was finally decided that in view of the Secretary’s instructions, I was obliged to submit a report in a broader framework, in greater detail and with a somewhat different emphasis than the reparations references included in the Departmental CFM paper on German economic problems. There is no inconsistency, however, between Departmental CFM references and the attached reparations proposals.”

  2. The reference here is presumably to Secretary Marshall’s proposal regarding the level of German industry and reparations from current production, circulated to the Council of Foreign Ministers on April 3, 1947; for the full text, see Germany 1947–1949, p. 410 or Department of State Bulletin, April 13, 1947, pp. 652–653. Regarding this proposal, see also telegram 1167, Delsec 1385, April 2, from Moscow, p, 306.