Executive Secretariat Files

Briefing Book Paper

Reparation and Restitution Policy Toward Germany

Summary

1. Nature of American Interest

A mistaken reparation policy may not only have adverse effects on the future economic stability of Europe but may jeopardize the political and economic objectives of this country with respect to Germany. For this reason German reparation should be supported only to the extent that it does not conflict with more important objectives.

2. Policy Recommendations.

a) Reparation should consist of the entire surplus above the output needed to maintain a minimum prescribed standard of living and to pay for relief, occupation costs and other prior charges. It should be made clear that the U. S. will not finance the transfer of reparation either directly or indirectly.

b) To minimize interference with normal trade the reparation period should be short: if possible five years, and in any event not over ten.

c) Reparation should be payable predominantly “in kind.” Labor services within reasonable limits should not be opposed provided a distinction is made in the treatment accorded to formerly active Nazis and politically passive Germans, respectively.

[Page 194]

d) The principal basis of apportionment should be damage to non-military property exclusive of current output. A supplementary basis, admissible only at a lower weighting, should be occupation costs. The reparation settlement should be considered as clearing finally all claims against Germany arising out of the war.

e) Germany should be obliged to restitute all identifiable stolen property. Gold and unique objects (but not other property) should be replaced with equivalents from German stocks if lost or destroyed.

f) United Nations should have the option of retaining and disposing of German property within their territories, the proceeds to be applied against reparation claims.

Reparation and Restitution Policy Toward Germany

1. Nature of American Interest

It is dangerous to assume, because the reparation claims of this country are likely to be very small, that we have little interest in the subject of reparation. Not only can an ill-conceived reparation policy give rise to mischievous consequences in itself but, what is even more important, it may jeopardize the achievement of the political and economic objectives of this country vis-à-vis Germany. For these reasons the reparation settlement with Germany is an issue of major importance to the United States.

Accordingly, the guiding principle of U. S. policy in regard to reparation should be that the reparation claims of our Allies should be supported only if, and to the extent that, such claims do not conflict with the other elements of the settlement with Germany. Reparation policies must conform and be subordinate to the security and economic measures adopted with respect to Germany; these measures should not be modified or weakened to enable Germany to pay more reparation.

Conceived thus as a “residual”, the reparation program will be determined, in its main outlines, by prior decisions with regard to industrial controls, export restrictions, territorial adjustments, etc. which may be imposed on Germany. For example, if chief reliance for economic security is placed on selective prohibitions and controls, Germany may be able (barring extreme war damage) to deliver a large volume of reparation goods out of current production. If, on the other hand, large sections of German industry are to be permanently dismantled, the bulk of reparation payments would necessarily take the form of transfers of existing German capital equipment, rather than of current output, and the total volume of reparation deliveries is likely to be comparatively small. Similarly, restriction of exports for commercial reasons, or important transfers of territory, would likewise affect the amount and form of reparation.

[Page 195]

The following recommendations with regard to reparation are intended to be consistent with the proposals of the State Department for the economic treatment of Germany.1 They make no assumption with respect to territorial changes.

2. Reparation Policy Recommendations

The most important elements of the German reparation program will be (a) its “weight”, (b) its duration, (c) its form, (d) the allocation of payments.

(a) In principle, the entire surplus above the output needed (1) to maintain a minimum prescribed standard of living, and (2) to pay for occupation costs, relief, and other prior charges, should be appropriated for reparation.

It would probably be desirable to make it clear to the other interested powers that the U.S. will not finance the transfer of reparation either directly by extending loans or credits to Germany, or indirectly by assuming the burden of supplying at its own expense essential goods or equipment to Germany.

In order to avoid difficulties with public opinion in the Allied countries, which is likely to regard any given amount of reparation as inadequate to compensate for the damage and suffering inflicted by Germany, as well as for other reasons, the statement of the reparation obligation in terms of a specific monetary amount should be avoided.

(b) It is essential for the early recovery of normal trade that the reparation program should be of relatively short duration. The uncompensated, one-way, transfers of reparation goods from Germany must necessarily interfere with the export trade of other countries. The longer reparation lasts, moreover, the more strongly is Germany likely to become entrenched in the markets of the claimant states; the more difficult, also, will be the readjustment of both paying and receiving countries at the end of the reparation period. The interference with normal trade may be relatively slight in the first two or three years after the war when trading conditions are in any case apt to be highly abnormal and the overall supply of goods may fall short of reconstruction needs and deferred demands. Beyond that time, however, the interference with normal trade will become progressively greater. It is recommended, accordingly, that the reparation period should be limited, if possible, to five years, and in any event should not exceed ten years.

(c) To avoid “transfer” difficulties, the reparation obligation should be payable preponderantly “in kind”, i. e., in goods and services, rather than in foreign exchange. The goods should be such as Germany is able to deliver and the claimant countries are willing to receive, both conditions being necessary for “transferability”.

[Page 196]

United Nations claiming reparation from Germany, in addition to being entitled to payments in kind, should have the option of retaining and disposing of all German property and rights within their territories and to apply the proceeds against their reparation claims.

The Soviet Government will probably demand, in satisfaction of part its reparation claim, the performance of labor services by German manpower in Russia. There is no compelling reason for the United States to oppose such claims within reasonable limits, provided that in the conscription of the labor force a distinction is made between formerly active Nazis and politically passive Germans, with minimum standards of treatment and a relatively short period of service for the latter.

(d) The principal basis for the apportionment of reparation among the claimant states should be the amount of damage to and loss of non-military property, exclusive of current output, caused by or incident to hostilities. As a supplementary basis of allocation, occupation costs (including for this purpose clearing balances accrued in Germany during the occupation period) should also be allowed as an admissible claim, but at a lower weighting than property losses. The reparation settlement should be considered as clearing finally all outstanding claims against Germany arising out of the war.

3. Restitution

The following policy recommendations are made:

(a)
In principle there should be an unlimited obligation on Germany to restore identifiable stolen property. In practice, however, official efforts to locate such property will have to be confined to a limited number of categories such as art treasures, securities, machinery, rolling stock, et cetera.
(b)
Looted property should be returned by a Restitution Commission to the Government having jurisdiction over the territory where the property had its situs and not to the former owners individually. The Commission should not be burdened with the task of deciding disputes with respect to ownership, liens, etc. Such questions, whether intra-national, or involving two or more countries, should be adjudicated in the place from which the property was taken.
(c)
All property transferred to Germany during the period of German occupation should be presumed to have been transferred under duress and accordingly treated as looted property.

The British Government has been pressing in the European Advisory Commission for the early establishment of a Restitution Commission to cope with the complex problems of restitution which will arise as soon as enemy territory is occupied to any appreciable extent. This Government has indicated its general approval of the British proposal, subject to certain reservations.

[Page 197]

The French have also introduced a proposal for restitution into the European Advisory Commission. Their concept of “restitution”, however, apparently goes far beyond the mere restoration of identifiable objects and would include the replacement of lost or destroyed objects with similar or equivalent goods found in Germany at the time of surrender. It is believed that such a broad application of the principle of replacement is undesirable. Claims for lost or destroyed property should be embraced in the reparation settlement; “replacement” should be confined to unique objects such as art treasures, and possibly gold.

4. German Foreign Holdings

“German” property in neutral and satellite countries can be divided into three categories:

1.
Looted Property. This is not properly German property, and the principle of restitution has already been indicated.
2.
Flight Capital. This is property which is and has been leaving Germany for refuge from post-hostilities Allied control. Efforts are now being made to have the neutrals prevent ingress of such property, and to segregate and control that which has already left Germany.
3.
German Foreign Investment. Control over this property is essential to the control of the German economic system. Cooperative U. S. and U. K. efforts are being made to conduct a census of such property, to have it segregated, and make it available for such disposition as may be agreed on among the Allies.

A coordinated effort, particularly directed at the neutrals, to control these classes of property is being made. The United States, United Kingdom, and USSR, among others of the United Nations, have cooperated in the issuance and endorsement of the following documents: Declaration of January 5, 1943, declaring a policy of refusal to recognize Axis acts of dispossession, in whatever form;2 Gold Declaration of February 22, 1944, declaring a policy of refusal to purchase gold from nations which have not ceased gold purchases, directly or indirectly, from the Axis;3 Bretton Woods Resolution VI, calling on neutrals to take appropriate action with respect to loot, flight capital, and German foreign investment.4

  1. The footnote in the original at this point refers to the preceding paper entitled “Economic Policies Toward Germany”.
  2. Department of State Bulletin, January 9, 1943. vol. viii, pp. 21–22.
  3. Treasury Department Notice, published in the Federal Register, February 23, 1944, vol. 9, p. 2096.
  4. Proceedings and Documents of the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, July 122, 1944 (Washington, Government Printing Office, 1948), vol. i, pp. 939–940.